Home » Discriminating Price Determination: Concept, Justification, and Diagrammatic Explanation

Discriminating Price Determination: Concept, Justification, and Diagrammatic Explanation

Price Determination
Spread the love

Introduction

In the study of microeconomics, pricing decisions made by firms are central to understanding market behavior. Under conditions of monopoly or market power, a seller is not bound to charge a uniform price for a product. Instead, the seller may charge different prices for the same commodity in different markets or from different consumers. This practice is known as price discrimination, and the process through which such discriminatory prices are set is called discriminating price determination.

Price discrimination plays a crucial role in analyzing the behavior of monopolists, public utilities, and firms with some degree of market control. It raises important questions of economic justification, welfare impact, and fairness, making it a vital topic for both theoretical and applied economics.



Meaning of Discriminating Price Determination

Definition:
Discriminating price determination refers to the process of setting different prices for the same good or service sold to different consumers or in different markets, without a corresponding difference in production cost.

For example:

  • A doctor may charge wealthy patients more than poorer ones for the same treatment.

  • Electricity supplied to households may be priced differently from electricity supplied to industries.

  • A monopolist may sell the same product at a higher price in a domestic market and a lower price in foreign markets.

In essence, it is charging “what the market will bear” under given conditions.



Types of Price Discrimination

Economist A.C. Pigou classified price discrimination into three degrees:

1. First-Degree Price Discrimination (Perfect Price Discrimination)

  • The seller charges each consumer the maximum price they are willing to pay.
  • Consumer surplus is fully converted into producer surplus.
  • Example: Auction sales, personalized online pricing with big data.

2. Second-Degree Price Discrimination

  • Prices vary according to the quantity purchased or product version, not consumer identity.
  • Example: Bulk discounts, electricity slab rates, mobile data packs.

3. Third-Degree Price Discrimination

  • Different prices are charged in different sub-markets, based on elasticity of demand.

  • Example: Train tickets (higher fare in peak hours, lower in off-peak), student and senior citizen discounts, higher export pricing.



Conditions for Price Discrimination

Price discrimination is possible only when certain conditions are satisfied:

  1. Monopoly or Market Power: The seller must have some control over price.

  2. Market Segmentation: The firm must be able to divide consumers into sub-markets.

  3. Different Price Elasticities of Demand: Each market must have a different demand elasticity.

  4. Prevention of Arbitrage: Consumers from low-price markets should not resell to high-price markets.

  5. No Legal Restrictions: Laws or ethics should not forbid differential pricing.



Process of Discriminating Price Determination

The monopolist aims to maximize total profit by charging different prices in different markets. The steps involved are:

  1. Segregate Markets: Divide total demand into sub-markets with varying elasticity.

  2. Determine Demand and MR: Draw demand (AR) and marginal revenue (MR) curves for each sub-market.

  3. Aggregate MR Curve: Add up the MR curves of each sub-market horizontally to get the combined MR curve.

  4. Equilibrium with MC Curve: The monopolist determines equilibrium output where aggregate MR = MC.

  5. Allocate Output: This equilibrium output is distributed between sub-markets in such a way that MR in each market equals MC.

  6. Fix Prices: Prices are fixed separately for each market based on their respective demand conditions.



Diagrammatic Explanation of Discriminating Price Determination

1. Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Let us assume there are two sub-markets:

  • Market A: Relatively inelastic demand.
  • Market B: Relatively elastic demand.

Step 1: Draw separate AR and MR curves for both markets.

  • Market A: Steeper demand curve (inelastic).
  • Market B: Flatter demand curve (elastic).

Step 2: Derive the combined MR curve by horizontally adding MR curves of both markets.

Step 3: Superimpose the MC curve of the monopolist.

  • Equilibrium occurs where combined MR = MC, giving the total output.

Step 4: Distribute total output across markets such that MR in Market A = MR in Market B = MC.

Step 5: Identify prices from AR curves in each market.

  • Price is higher in Market A (inelastic demand).
  • Price is lower in Market B (elastic demand).

Conclusion from Diagram:
The monopolist charges a higher price in less elastic markets and a lower price in more elastic markets, ensuring maximum profits.



Is Discriminating Price Determination Justified Economically?

Arguments in Favor

  1. Profit Maximization:
    • It allows monopolists to capture a larger consumer surplus and increase profits.

  2. Cross-Subsidization:
    • Essential goods can be sold cheaply to the poor (inelastic markets) while charging higher prices to rich consumers or in luxury markets.

    • Example: Railways charging more for AC coaches and less for sleeper class.

  3. Promotes Output Expansion:
    • Discrimination often leads to higher total output than under uniform pricing.

    • Some consumers who could not afford the good at a uniform high price can access it under discriminatory pricing.

  4. Encourages Innovation and Investment:
    • Higher profits through discrimination may fund research, innovation, and better services.

  5. International Trade Benefits:
    • Dumping (charging lower prices abroad) can help firms utilize surplus production and compete globally.



Arguments Against

  1. Exploitation of Consumers:
    • Higher prices in inelastic markets exploit consumers with fewer alternatives.

  2. Inequality:
    • Wealthier sections may be charged less (bulk discounts) compared to poorer consumers buying in smaller quantities.

  3. Restriction of Consumer Surplus:
    • Price discrimination reduces consumer welfare as surplus shifts to producers.

  4. Encouragement of Monopoly Power:
    • Sustains monopoly and discourages competition.

  5. Social Unfairness:
    • Differential pricing of essential goods may be seen as socially unjust.



Economic Justification

Despite criticisms, economists generally recognize that discriminating price determination can be economically justified under certain conditions:

  • If it leads to greater efficiency and output expansion.

  • If it helps in cross-subsidizing essential services (e.g., electricity, railways, education).

  • If it promotes social welfare by making products affordable to low-income consumers.

  • If it sustains industries producing goods of strategic or national importance.

In short, while it redistributes surplus from consumers to producers, it can also expand total welfare in specific scenarios.



Real-World Examples of Discriminating Price Determination

  1. Indian Railways:
    • Different prices for AC, sleeper, and general class passengers.

  2. Airlines:
    • Different fares for business class, economy class, and advance bookings.

  3. Electricity Tariffs:
    • Lower rates for domestic consumers, higher rates for industries.

  4. Pharmaceutical Industry:
    • Different prices for medicines in developed and developing countries.

  5. Education Sector:
    • Scholarships and fee waivers for needy students, full fees for wealthy students.



Conclusion

Discriminating price determination is a common practice under monopoly and imperfect competition where firms charge different prices for the same product in different markets or from different consumers. It is made possible by variations in demand elasticity, market segmentation, and prevention of arbitrage.

  • In theory, price discrimination redistributes consumer surplus to producers, often reducing equity.

  • In practice, it can be economically justified if it leads to output expansion, social welfare, or cross-subsidization.

Diagrammatically, the monopolist achieves equilibrium by setting combined MR = MC and then allocating output across sub-markets, charging higher prices where demand is less elastic and lower prices where demand is more elastic.

Thus, while critics view it as exploitative, economists argue that in many real-world situations—such as public utilities, international trade, and education—discriminating price determination is not only justified but also socially desirable.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *